18.04.2020

How to apply the method of the two-circuit monetary system of the USSR. Double-loop economy according to nine


Yesterday I came across an interesting book and remembered a few srachs caused by the mention of multi-circuit monetary system in the USSR. If briefly about the essence of a multi-circuit system, then in a magical country called the USSR, the money of the industrial and consumer spheres did not mix. At the same time, to build a plant, it was enough to create an account for this plant in the State Bank and draw on this account a word of three letters, the last "y" any arbitrary amount, cast the necessary spell from the Diamat witchcraft school, select free units with the mouse and send them for construction.

So, I open that very interesting book called "Money circulation and credit in the USSR" authored by Gusakov A. D. and Dymshits I. A. 1951 edition on page 213:

Non-cash and cash payments. The concept of payment turnover.
With all the diversity and interweaving of settlement relations, they can be reduced to two main groups, each of which has its own characteristic features:
a) the sphere of settlement relations within the socialist economy, embracing economic settlements between socialist enterprises and organizations, as well as their settlements with the financial and credit systems;
b) the sphere of settlement relations of socialist enterprises and organizations, including the financial and credit system, with the population.

The distinguishing feature of the first sphere is that cash move within the limits of the socialized economy and the participants in monetary settlements are state and cooperative enterprises and organizations. Therefore, there is a direct state regulation of all economic, and hence settlement relations. An example of such regulation is Soviet legislation, which obliges all state and cooperative enterprises and organizations to keep their money in accounts with credit institutions and settle among themselves in a non-cash manner by transferring the appropriate amounts from the accounts of payers to the accounts of suppliers, financial agencies or banks.

Such direct regulation cannot be, and is not required in the second area, hallmark which is that one of the participants in the calculations is the population, which manages its income, after the fulfillment monetary obligations before the state at its discretion. State regulation in this area is aimed at ensuring the planned ratio between income and expenditure of the population based on determining the level of its cash income and commodity and non-commodity expenditures, as well as their territorial distribution (see Chapter Nine). From the specified feature of the second sphere cash flow the main method of payment inherent in it follows - with the help of cash.

Cashless settlements in the socialized economy and cash settlements between socialist enterprises and organizations and the population and the population with the socialized economy are the two main forms of money circulation in socialist society.

With non-cash payments, all monetary relations are formalized without the participation of cash, by making entries in the accounts of payers and recipients. This applies to all the various forms of non-cash payments between socialist enterprises and organizations.

In these calculations, money appears primarily as means of payment, which is typical for monetary relations in the first area. Such monetary relations are special form turnover of funds - non-cash payment turnover.

Non-cash payment turnover occurs through credit institutions, which not only store financial resources and maintain the accounts of participants in non-cash settlements, but also actively organize such settlements. Thanks to this feature of the payment turnover non-cash payments are the most important link in the whole system bank control ruble for the work of economic organizations.

The purpose of cash circulation is mainly to serve the process of distributing articles of personal consumption in accordance with the principle of socialism: "from each according to his ability, to each according to his work." In this turnover, money acts primarily as a medium of circulation, which is typical for monetary relations in the second sphere.

Aha! Here it is a two-circuit system! But it was not there, the ruthless authors do not calm down and continue:

Non-cash payments and cash transactions are different forms of a unified system of cash payments. Moreover, both of these forms of payment are constantly intertwined: cash transactions become a source for non-cash payments, and these latter are transferred to cash. Thus, trade, entertainment, household and other enterprises and organizations serving the population hand over their proceeds to the State Bank, which credits it to the accounts of these organizations; in the future, these receipts serve as a source for non-cash transfers to suppliers and financial authorities. Suppliers, on whose accounts non-cash payments have been received, receive cash from the cash desks of the State Bank for issuing wages, payment for agricultural preparations and for other needs. In the same way, funds received by bank transfer to the accounts state budget from socialist enterprises, serve as a source for the payment of pensions, benefits and other payments to the population, made in the form of cash.

Something like that.

Post-war Russia was closed from the invasion of the biblical credit financial system state monopoly of foreign trade, having built a three-circuit credit and financial system in which:

- the first circuit - currency circulation ensured foreign trade under the state monopoly on export-import operations, which excluded direct financial management from outside national economy USSR;

- the second circuit - non-cash ruble internal circulation served the production system in the state and cooperative-collective farm sectors of the economy;

- third circuit - cash monetary circulation served the system retail and individual labor activity, although the number of individual farmers (private entrepreneurs) and the volume of production of marketable products and services by them were negligible in relation to the volume of production in the state and cooperative-collective farm sectors

Basically nothing in the credit and financial system as such, built on these principles, it did not hurt to admit private entrepreneurs to it - workers, organizers of collective activities. If at the same time their personal family income, which they can spend on personal and family consumption, were limited to a level that precludes the possibility of "fat frenzy", and would be guaranteed freedom to invest in socially useful production, the result would be much more efficient economy than the economy of any of the capitalist countries; the result would be an economy that expresses a different - truly universal - morality and ethics (in the sense of uniting people on the basis of moral and ethical principles common to all of them).

And the three-loop system of the credit and financial system was effective as long as until the inertia of the era of Stalinism was exhausted and there was no crowding out in leading positions in the party, in the state apparatus, in science and in industries, and Agriculture creators-professionals of the Stalin era as grabbers and weak-willed opportunists, alien to the ideas of socialism or incapable of defending them in politics (out of cowardice and lack of will).

How did the two-circuit system of monetary circulation of the USSR work!

Let's start with the fact that in Soviet Russia there were no two main resources for industrialization - labor and energy. Potentially, there were many workers - 80% of the country's population lived in the countryside, picking dry soil. But for industrialization it was necessary to release these working hands, that is, to raise the productivity of labor in agriculture. If one peasant produces twice as much bread, milk and radishes, then the second one can be put to the machine. If we simply remove 30-40 million workers from the countryside, then food production will fall by half and the country will suffer famine.

Collectivization solved this problem - the village was unloaded from "extra" people, mostly young people who managed to go to school for at least a few years, while agricultural production in the USSR, thanks to mechanization, not only did not fall, but increased noticeably. This was precisely the purpose of collectivization.

With the energy sector, everything was much more complicated, but even here success is evident: electricity generation in 1932 compared to 1913 increased almost 7 times, from 2 to 13.5 billion kWh. The complexity of the matter was due to the fact that within the IV techno-structure, the critical technologies were precisely the production of electric motors and electric generators, internal combustion engines and jet engines. Critical technologies are those technologies that provide the industrial power that owns them with a qualitative advantage over others. Therefore, critical technologies are NOT FOR SALE. Electric motors and jet planes are sold, but their production technologies are not! Who wants to argue with this - try today to buy, for example, a license for the production of an iPhone. You can't do this for any amount of money.

So, in the USSR there are tens of millions of peasants who are ready to become workers, and there is electricity, without which industry is unthinkable. It remains to find the third resource necessary for industrialization - financial. Without money (investment), the economy cannot develop. If it costs 100 million to build a plant, then take them out, but suppose it, otherwise there will be no plant.

money could give foreign investors, and the Soviet government was ready for any conditions, up to the recognition of royal debts in exchange for investments. The capitalists proudly refused ... The total share of all foreign investment(credits) to the industrialization of the USSR - about 4%.

Money can be borrowed from the public. According to this scheme, in Egypt, the government implemented in just a year, instead of the planned three, the construction of the second Suez Canal (backup channel). The $8.5 billion needed to implement the project was collected in just 8 days, during which the people of Egypt bought up all the loan bonds issued to finance the mega-building.

However, in the USSR at the end of the 1920s, the population was poor. Yes, government bonds were sold, but in 1928-1929. they provided only 0.8 billion rubles. out of 7.7 billion costs. In 1932, the Soviet government spent 27.5 billion rubles on the needs of industrialization, of which only 4 billion rubles were withdrawn from the population voluntarily-compulsorily through the sale of bonds. In total, in the first two five-year plans, “internal investments” provided about 23% of all investments. Where did the remaining 100-4-23 = 73% of the cost of industrialization come from?

I will tell you a great secret - Comrade Stalin literally took investments out of thin air - he simply “printed” the necessary tens of billions of rubles and distributed them to enterprises at 0% per annum. Hundreds of billions would have to be needed - and hundreds would have been "printed". I write the word “printed” in quotes, because in fact no one printed anything, the rubles were non-cash, completely virtual.

Someone will be surprised: they say, this is impossible, if tens of billions of rubles suddenly pour into the market, this will cause wild hyperinflation, because they are not provided with consumer goods! So, Comrade Stalin was not a fool, he understood political economy issues ... In order to prevent tens of billions of UNCOVERED rubles from breaking into the consumer market, a second completely closed financial circuit was created in the country, nowhere intersecting with the circuit of "cash" money.

Roughly speaking, each enterprise opened a special account with the State Bank, where these "investment" funds were transferred. non-cash rubles. Since they were non-cash and in principle could not be cashed out, settlements in this circuit were made exclusively between enterprises and the state. For example, a tractor plant could buy machine tools from a machine-tool plant and pay in non-cash rubles in the "investment" circuit. And the machine-tool plant, having received a million of these non-cash rubles from the tractor, immediately bought rolled steel at the metallurgical plant; he bought coal from the mine; the mine purchased excavators and bulldozers from a tractor factory.

That's how this money was rushing around in a circle, only the numbers on the accounts of these enterprises' special accounts in the State Bank changed. The dual-loop financial system solved the problem of investment hunger completely. No matter how much money the economy needed, they were issued with one stroke of the pen. The restrictions for the investor were dictated by physical factors - if there are no workers for the construction of the plant, then there is no need to print money for "investment".

In this case, there is a need to increase labor productivity. This problem was solved by the Stakhanov movement (the movement of inventors and innovators). Labor productivity increased by 5% in a year? Has the production of steel and iron increased, do miners give out more coal to the mountain? Have railroad workers reduced the empty mileage of wagons? Have the oilmen increased the overhaul period of wells? Excellent! This means that we can build a couple of hundred additional plants - there are no problems with investments from the word “absolutely”.

Why did the injection of astronomical sums into circulation not cause hyperinflation? Because non-cash rubles existed only in the form of entries in the books of employees of the State Bank. This "investment" money could not be received by miners and combine operators in the form of wages, and therefore they did not put pressure on the consumer market, they did not provoke a rise in prices. And "effective managers" could not steal them - how to steal non-cash? Yes, and there is no point in stealing, because to buy with this money a common person can't do anything. It is even stupid to talk about the flight of capital abroad.

But inflation during the first five-year plans was quite noticeable. Why did it arise? Let me remind you that 80% of the population lived in the countryside and did not receive a salary. Peasants in the 1920s led a backward semi-subsistence economy and, in principle, could do without money. But when millions of rural residents moved to the cities, they became participants in commodity-money relations. They no longer took potatoes from the garden, but bought goods in the store. Accordingly, in addition to the "investment" ones, the state also issued the most ordinary paper rubles and copper kopecks, which are necessary for the functioning of retail trade and the service sector.

But if the workers build Magnitka and Turksib, then they get a big salary, and there are no more consumer goods. Consumer goods produce light industry, which cannot develop until heavy industry is created. Accordingly, while the main efforts in the Soviet Union were concentrated on creating the base of the economy - metallurgy, energy complex, the transport system, heavy engineering, the money supply in the hands of the population increased, and the consumer market, which was growing extremely slowly, could not digest it. This caused inflation.

If anyone is very surprised, then I inform you: no one worked for free in the USSR, moreover, the main incentive for hard work was precisely material, since our wages were not “socialist” equalization, as in the factories of the capitalist Ford. We were dominated by the most "capitalist" of all possible piecework systems of payment. If you want to get more - turn more bushings than planned.

The Stakhanovist movement is, of course, good, but it leads to an increase in wages, an increase in wages entails a decrease in the purchasing power of the ruble, and this in turn undermines the financial incentive. What is the point of working hard, sparing no effort, if you can’t buy anything with the salary you receive?

It was to fight inflation that the state issued those famous government bonds of industrial loans. That is, the workers were paid a good salary, and then some were actually forcibly taken back. Like, why do you, comrade, need such crazy thousands? Let's take them away from you for now, and in 10 years, when light industry enterprises will start working in our country, the state will return this money to you, and even with interest - then you will buy calico, a gramophone, a ticket to a sanatorium in Sochi and other pleasant nishtyaks. Soviet state loans did not solve any other problem.

The result is obvious: the industry at the level of the leading powers of that time in the USSR was built in the shortest possible time and almost exclusively at the expense of internal resources. Let me remind you that the volume of external investments (loans), although very impressive in physical terms and very important in terms of borrowing technology, did not exceed 4% of the total investment. We raised the fuel and energy complex thanks to the bourgeoisie, we got working hands thanks to the successfully implemented collectivization, but the most effective investment mechanism in the world - a two-circuit financial system - is our Russian know-how.

The question is: is it possible to apply a fantastically effective mechanism of a two-circuit financial system without the State Planning Commission, the Gulag and Comrade Stalin, who watches over all this? Of course! Already in 1934, the two-circuit financial system was implemented by Hjalmar Schacht in Germany, which was a completely market and capitalist country. True, the scale of the tasks to be solved there was immeasurably smaller. Germany, exhausted by the world economic crisis, required huge money for armaments. Where can I get them?

That's why Shakht copied and pasted the second financial circuit from the Soviets, in which non-cash stamps circulated. Well, in general, the task of revitalizing the economy with the help of domestic investment was also resolved quite successfully - within a few months, the Germans in terms of economic growth came in second place after the Russians. But, I emphasize, in the Third Reich, growth was of a restorative nature, and not of a qualitative nature, as in the USSR, since the industry already existed in Germany, it was only necessary to spin the flywheel of production. The dual-circuit financial system allowed Germany to restore its military power in the shortest possible time without dropping standard of living population, and even noticeably raising it.

First

Chapter 11. Soviet ruble: cash and non-cash. about the two-circuit monetary system of Stalin's economy

Today, the ideology of economic liberalism and the practice of market reforms in our country have completely discredited themselves. Against this background, there was an increased interest in the theory and practice of economic construction in the USSR, especially in Stalin's economy, which is chronologically defined by the period 1930-1960. We have already noted above that an important element of Stalin's economy was the so-called two-loop monetary system.

This text is an introductory piece. From the book History of World Civilizations author Fortunatov Vladimir Valentinovich

Chapter 4 The Soviet "challenge" to the West and the Soviet "example" for

From the book From the Invasion of the Barbarians to the Renaissance. Life and work in medieval Europe author Boissonade Prosper

CHAPTER 4 money economy and the development of trade in the West from the middle of the X to the middle of the XIV century. Ever since the brief economic renaissance of the Carolingian era ended in failure, the subsistence or estate economy has been steadily gaining momentum. First

From the book History of Portugal author Saraiva José Ermanu

23. The success of the commodity-money economy During the XIII and XIV centuries. developing internal and international trade and the linkage between trade and agriculture is being strengthened. This is not a purely Portuguese phenomenon, but a trend seen throughout Western Europe. Development

From the book History of Russia author Munchaev Shamil Magomedovich

§ 1. The Soviet Union in political system post-war world History of the Soviet state after graduation Patriotic War, since the second half of the 40s and 80s. characterized to a large extent by bright pages. Unfortunately, many publications recent years these

From the book Mysteries of Lend-Lease author Stettinius Edward

CHAPTER 2 Cash, No Delivery On May 28, 1940, the phone rang in my office in New York and I was informed in a businesslike tone: - Mr. Stettinius, there is a call from the White House for you. The president wants to talk to you. Mr. Roosevelt was brief. He reported that before

author Katasonov Valentin Yurievich

On the planned character of Stalin's economy Particular attention should be paid to the planned character of the economy. Critics of the Stalinist model, using the derogatory phrase "administrative-command system", primarily have in mind the national economic

From the book Economics of Stalin author Katasonov Valentin Yurievich

On the monetary system of the Stalinist economy They can be called credit, banking, monetary, financial subsystems. All subsystems were organically interconnected. In fact, they formed single system, within which money was created, was regulated

From the book Development of Soviet Aviation in the Pre-War Period (1938 - first half of 1941) author Stepanov Alexey Sergeevich

Chapter 1. The Soviet aircraft industry - the pride of the domestic military economy

From the book Sea Secrets of the Ancient Slavs author Dmitrenko Sergey Georgievich

On the monetary system of Ancient Russia (VII-IX centuries) One of the indicators of close economic ties Russia with the Arab East is the device of the ancient Russian monetary and financial system. “Since in Pravda Rosskaya we meet with monetary and monetary

From the book Who stole my USSR? by Asher Eli

Chapter 3. Nikolai Ryzhkov - the man who stole the Soviet ruble So, the anti-alcohol decree was a volley on the economy, but ... this was not enough. First of all, the economy and society is a living organism, and living organisms are not easy to kill. They change and

09 December 2014

Very interesting article!
Here are some excerpts from it...
*********************
https://cont.ws/post/233303
Author: Kurman Akhmetov, source: Kazakh newspaper Svoboda Slova No. 1 (145), No. 2 (146) and No. 3 (147) - January 2008.

PARADOXICAL FINANCIAL SYSTEM OF THE USSR


Have you ever wondered, dear reader, how much money can circulate in a market economy? Surely not. Meanwhile, the amount of money in circulation is well known to science and is described by the so-called elementary identity of the quantitative theory of money: MV = PQ. (There are more complex formulas, but let's take the simplest one). Translated into human language, this formula means: the mass of money, multiplied by the velocity of circulation, must equal the mass of realized (sold) goods, expressed in prices. In other words, how much goods are sold in the economy, exactly how much money should circulate in it.

Let's say, if a billion worth of goods are sold in the economy, exactly one billion worth of money should circulate in it. And if a hundred billion worth of goods have been sold, then exactly one hundred billion worth of money should circulate. If more is drawn - this is already inflation. If less, then (to balance both parts of the identity) either a decline in production occurs, or prices fall, or the money supply increases.


Let's pay attention to one circumstance. With the exception of industries financed from the budget, the entire production sector in a market economy is paid for from the proceeds from the sale of consumer goods and redistributed upwards vertically. Let's say, if a farmer buys a tractor, then, ultimately, the cost of this tractor is paid by the consumer of bread products. And if a company produces machine tools, then the production of these machines is ultimately paid not by the one who bought them, but by the one who purchased the products made on these machines.

Everything is invested in the price of the final consumer product: the cost of energy resources, and transportation costs, and payment for raw materials, and deductions to the budget, and much more. Bank lending calculated on the reimbursement of loans and interest on them from future income received, again, from the sale of consumer goods, i.e. and loans are built into the price of final consumer products. In a market economy, the consumer sector is dominant, and the entire economy is based on it. Any market economy is based on personal consumption, which is directly related to personal income citizens. Yes, all over the world. So it was in the USSR. But at what level? The well-known researcher Yuri Emelyanov writes: “By the end of 1924, the country's industry produced extremely little and only the most primitive products. Metallurgy could provide each peasant economy Russia only 64 grams of nails annually. If the level of development of industry would continue to remain at this level, then the peasant, having bought a plow and a harrow, could expect to acquire these items for himself again only in 2045. The country was faced with the task in full growth: either to reverse the economic situation, or to perish.

Revolution in the economy

It is clear that in the economy of such an underdeveloped country, an extremely small amount of money turned around. The death of the state seemed inevitable. The breakthrough in the economy began in 1929. During the first Soviet five-year plan, from 1929 to 1933, about 1500 large industrial enterprises and entire industries that did not exist before were created: machine-tool building, aviation, chemical, ferroalloy production, tractor building, automotive industry and others. A second industrial center was created beyond the Urals (the first in the European part of the country), a circumstance that ultimately decided the outcome of the Great Patriotic War. Large-scale transformations required huge investments. But there was no money for investments.

In the first year of the five-year plan industrial development was funded by only 36%. In the second year - by 18%. And by the end of the five-year period, funding fell to zero. By 1937 the total industrial production increased in comparison with 1928 by almost 4 times. It turned out a paradoxical thing: investments were reduced to zero, and production increased several times. This was achieved using a method that has not yet been used in the history of the economy: the money supply was divided into cash and non-cash parts.

In fact, money is not cash and non-cash. Cash or non-cash is a form of payment or a form of savings. The splitting of money in the Soviet economy into mutually non-convertible parts meant the actual destruction of money as a universal equivalent. Non-cash money in such a system serves mainly as a means of accounting. In essence, this is not money, but counting units, with the help of which material resources are distributed. This has been pointed out by many for a long time. Cash in the Soviet economic system, as well as non-cash, had nothing to do with real money backed by the mass of commodities and served as a means of distributing material wealth, regardless of real labor productivity.

As a result of the transformation of the monetary system Soviet economy ceased to be dependent on the consumer sector. In a market economy, all savings and, accordingly, investments are created from profits from the sale of consumer goods and vertical redistribution, and the scale of the economy expands as the consumer sector expands. In the Soviet-type economy, on the contrary, it is the consumer sector that is in a subordinate position; beginning in 1929, the Soviet economy began to develop in a way that was directly opposite to the market. First of all, the task was to create a defense complex, then mechanical engineering, mechanization of agriculture, creation housing, electrification, etc. And only in the second place is the production of consumer goods.

ingenious solution

Since then, it has been that way. In 1940, 39% of all industrial output in the USSR was consumer goods. In 1980, its share was 26.2%. In 1986 it was 24.7%. The consumer sector in the USSR occupied not only an extremely insignificant place, but was also underdeveloped purely physically. This means an elementary lack of appropriate production capacity: only about 13% of the total production capacity of the Soviet Union was occupied by the production of consumer products.

We know that, in general, the mass of money in an economy is equal to the mass of all goods sold, expressed in prices. In other words, everything depends on the scale of development of the consumer sector. all costs are built into the price of the final consumer product. After 1929, the backward Soviet economy made a breakthrough, and an unrelated mass of industries and infrastructure hung over the consumer sector, the simple financial maintenance of which required a money supply many times greater than that corresponding to the existing mass of commodities.

The decision to divide the money supply into two independent spheres - cash and non-cash - was, no doubt, brilliant. It allowed the country in the shortest possible time to go through a path that, with the normal development of processes, would have taken several centuries (at best). Such a solution of theoretically absolutely insoluble problems was the only possible one in those specific historical conditions, with those production resources that were available, and at that level of technical development.

This solution was not found immediately, but empirically, empirically. The financial system created in the USSR had no analogues in history. It came into such striking contrast with all the experience accumulated by economic science by that time that it took a whole ideological, and not scientific justification for its implementation. As a result, the principles of the Soviet financial system were so camouflaged with ideological constructs that they have not really been comprehended to this day. A breakthrough in the economy led to a complete change in its structure and the creation of an appropriate financial system. He set such a direction of development, in which the economy does not develop in accordance with the growth of personal consumption, but, on the contrary, consumption grows following the increase in the possibilities of the economy.

"Inverted" economy

In an economy structured "in the Soviet way", the consumer sector is not economically significant at all. Changes in personal consumption here affect the economy to a limited extent. The desperate struggle for the creation of a defense complex in the 30s, the Second World War, the need to overcome the post-war devastation and the arms race consolidated the situation. The need to forcefully raise the standard of living of the population in the 1950s and 1970s led to the same results. This is our main feature: we have an economy capable of producing the volume of consumer products equivalent to one money supply, and at the same time the amount of production, infrastructure and social security systems, the financial maintenance of which requires another, larger money supply. Moreover, the second is many times greater than the first.

In addition, the consumer sector and the rest of our economy, as a rule, are almost unrelated. The flow of finance is generally excluded here, even if more than enough money is poured into the economy. Under the Soviet system, this problem was solved by strictly separating the two sectors of the financial system and distributing cash (cash and non-cash) flows in a planned manner. And the need for this was not dictated by Marxist theory, there is nothing of the kind in it. It is predetermined by the very structural characteristics of the economic system created in the USSR after 1929.

The Soviet financial system looks paradoxical from the point of view of Western economists. They simply could not understand it (and the "reformers" too). But in reality, it worked very well. Historically, we have formed an economy structured directly opposite to the Western one, “inverted” in comparison with it. In this "inverted" economy, we are trying to introduce the Western financial system. This is absurd. It is impossible to have one structure of the economy and a financial system designed for a completely different, directly opposite structure of the economy. It is impossible to have an economic structure “like ours” and a financial system “like theirs”. Recall that the economies of all the republics of the USSR were built in exactly this "Soviet" way - jerkily and disproportionately. Therefore, they all have similar structural characteristics. Accordingly, their financial systems also have similar characteristics. Financial and economic problems in general are about the same for them. In other words, both the financial and economic policies of the CIS countries should be carried out by approximately the same methods.

As we have indicated, starting from 1929 (from the beginning of industrialization), the Soviet economy began to develop in a way that was directly opposite to the market one. The market economy is based on the personal consumption of citizens, and in the USSR the consumer sector was not the main one, but a subordinate one. In addition, the Soviet economy, of necessity, was built in such a way that no competition could arise in it: exactly as many enterprises were built as needed for the needs of the economy. Such an economy precludes all competition by its very structure. Thus, the two main defining features of the economy former USSR the following:

1) relative underdevelopment of the consumer sector;

2) the almost complete absence of duplication production activities(competition) in the structure of the economy.

An economy structured in this way requires a specific financial system to ensure its normal functioning. Its essence is as follows. Money is divided into cash and non-cash spheres. Cash Serves purchasing power population. Non-cash "money" is essentially not money, but counting units, with the help of which the distribution of material resources is carried out in a planned manner.

Our advantages

During the “perestroika” period, such an economic structure became the object of heavy criticism from the “reformers”. However, the "reformers" did not present a serious analysis. As arguments, they used mostly emotions, and they presented the fact of criticality as truth. They could not offer something real either then or later. Moreover, some of them - such as, for example, Academician Petrakov, have now moved to directly opposite positions.

The physicist, Academician Yuri Kagan recalls with a caustic mockery of the “ideologists of reforms”: “In Soviet times, at the Kurchatov Institute, I led a seminar where all the leading economists spoke, who did not have a wide platform at that time - Shatalin, Aganbegyan, Zaslavskaya, Petrakov, Shmelev, Abalkin . They argued that the Soviet economy was leading to an abyss. I asked them: do you have an idea how to move from what is not needed to what is needed? They answered: we are not in demand, that's when we are in demand, we will write the necessary program in a month. So what came of it?"

In fact, the economic system built in the USSR, in addition to the well-known shortcomings, had very significant advantages over the Western (market) economy. These advantages are as follows:

1) The transition to a bifurcated financial system made it possible to free this economy from the limiting influence of the effective demand of the population, and it got the opportunity to develop independently of it. In the Western (market) economy, this is impossible. Everything there depends on effective demand: if it grows, the economy goes up; when it contracts, the economy is in recession;

2) Operation based non-cash money(more precisely, counting units) ruled out a situation in which development could be hampered due to a lack of financial resources. Here everything is determined by purely technical possibilities. And such a thing as non-payments or mutual debt simply cannot arise here; accordingly, economic paralysis cannot arise for this reason;

3) Organizational structure economy, excluding competition, allowed it, on the one hand, to reach the industrial level of development, on the other hand, to avoid the monstrous energy, resource and labor intensity of the Western (market) economy. Otherwise industrial country The USSR would never have: it simply would not have been able to overcome the barrier of energy and resource intensity;

4) Centralized system economic management made it possible to concentrate all efforts, resources and funds on selected areas, and to do this promptly, without waiting for this to happen as a result of an overflow of funds due to changes in market conditions, demand, etc.

In essence, the USSR developed a method for creating an economy more developed than the effective demand of the population allows. This valuable experience opens up new prospects for the economies of not only the CIS, but also other countries, and is still waiting to be studied and comprehended.

Objective assessment

In fact, a new type of economic system was created in the USSR, requiring special methods of management and special methods of reform. The fact that this is a fundamentally new, unprecedented in history and at the same time a very promising economic system was not comprehended in time either by the leaders of the state, let alone by the "reformers". Our "reformers", criticizing the Soviet economic system, they just repeated and still stupidly repeat the theses thrown to them from abroad. But after all, how much time has passed, it would be time to understand what was happening. As part of the Cold War, of course, psychological warfare was also waged. It included an attack on the thinking of intellectuals, writers, publicists, scientists, not least economists. It was suggested something like this: "Your economy is good for nothing, destroy it, do as we do." And they destroyed it. Now they are sitting on the ruins of the country and still cannot understand anything. In reality, however, serious Western researchers, free from ideological prejudices, have always highly appreciated the achievements of the Soviet economic system.

Thus, the English magazine The Economist writes: “Contrary to widespread statements, the historical development of the Soviet economy is one of the greatest successes achieved in the twentieth century. The USSR turned out to be one of two countries in the world that rapidly broke through into the group of industrially developed countries: the second country is Japan. Among largest countries In the world, only Japan exceeded the income level of GDP per capita of the USSR. This allowed the Soviet Union to eliminate extreme poverty, ensure the creation of services social insurance, create one of the most comprehensive social security systems in the world, achieve one of the high levels education and healthcare, to create a powerful military potential comparable to that of the United States. In addition to the defense industry, Soviet technology has proven its ability to prove itself at the highest international level. And all this - despite the blockade in the technological field by Western countries, from which Japan, by the way, did not suffer. Under these conditions, the development of the USSR is one of the largest economic achievements in world history.

Let us pay attention, however, to the following striking fact: the USSR achieved outstanding economic success, in all respects inferior to the West. The West (it should be considered as a single economic entity) consumes two-thirds of the resources extracted in the world. The USSR could always rely only on its own resources. Hundreds of millions of working hands are working in the West and hundreds of millions of working hands are working for it all over the world. There were only a few tens of millions of workers in the USSR. And the total industrial potential of the West exceeded the Soviet one not by hundreds, but by thousands of times. Nevertheless, the USSR managed to achieve phenomenal economic success and become the world's second superpower, although theoretically it had neither the strength nor the opportunity to do so. How did he do it? Thanks to that paradoxical (from the point of view of Western economists) structure of the economy and the corresponding paradoxical financial system. We have pointed out the advantages of the latter above.

Practice is the criterion of truth

From all that has been said, it does not at all follow that the Soviet economy was the pinnacle of perfection. Of course, it should have been reformed. But how? This question is difficult and complex. We will not consider it in its entirety. We will only touch upon the question of the financial system. The “reformers”, embarking on their destructive activities, considered it necessary to remove the barrier between the spheres of action of cash and non-cash money. It was a mistake. What should happen if such a barrier is removed in an economy structured in the “Soviet way”? In this case, the following should happen.

The bifurcated cash-non-cash financial system is liquidated, and the economy begins to work on the basis of real money backed by a mass of commodities. Since the economy, structured in the "Soviet way", creates a relatively small amount of consumer goods, the money supply immediately begins to shrink rapidly. As a result, the money supply is reduced to a level at which the normal functioning of the economy is impossible. Due to the general lack of money, financing of everything that is possible and impossible is stopped. A rapid decline in production begins, the situation immediately acquires a tendency to worsen. The effective demand of the population is constantly decreasing, which aggravates the already difficult situation. An increase in the money supply leads to an increase in prices. Strict regulation of the money supply in circulation exacerbates the general shortage of money. The budget is falling apart. The life support systems of the state are falling apart. Literally everything falls apart. "Reforms" come to a standstill.

In a word, during the years of "reforms" everything that should have happened happened. Everything was quite predictable. Conclusion: the problem of lack of money in our economy cannot be overcome - it is built into the very structure of the economic system at our disposal. Why were the economists silent? And they were not silent. Simply economically illiterate "reformers" were unable to understand them.

So, the famous economist V.M. Yakushev wrote back in 1989: “Rubles in relations between enterprises play the role not of money, but of accounting units (“money of account”), with the help of which the exchange of activities is mediated and labor costs are recorded. We have two types of money: "labor" and "accounting" and this is our reality. They cannot be mixed, and even more so, translated “countable” into “labor”. Planned and financial authorities unwittingly take into account this difference and insist that money from other items of expenditure should not be transferred to incentive funds. But this difference is not recognized by commodity-oriented economists, and instead of understanding why practitioners do this, they accuse them of thoughtlessness and ignorance, forgetting that practice is the criterion of truth. Now “accountable” money began to be abundantly transferred to the material incentive funds. And the result is that the financial system is practically disorganized.”

He was right. At that time, many wrote about it. Unfortunately, the management of economic processes fell into the hands of pseudo-economists, whose qualifications, to put it mildly, left much to be desired. They still have not understood and learned nothing. And what should have been done to stop the destruction of the economy? Bring the financial system back into line with the economic structure, that is, restore the barrier. The same Yakushev rightly wrote: “Organize financial relations it is possible only by blocking the transfer of “accounting” money into “labor” money. But this is not consistent with self-financing, which encourages such a spillover, based on the notion that we are dealing with ordinary commodity money. Recall that we are talking about the economy of the USSR as a general example. Everything that has been said about the economy of the former Soviet Union is also true for its constituent parts, since the entire Soviet economy was built according to a single scheme. It is from this that one must proceed.

So, until 1929, the USSR was an economically backward country, about 85% of whose population lived in countryside. In 1929, the country began an economic breakthrough - industrialization. Strictly speaking, it was from this moment that the Soviet economy began to be created. Since there was no money to finance industrialization in the country, the country's leadership found a paradoxical but effective solution: money was strictly divided into two areas of use - cash and non-cash. The scope of cash in such a system serves the immediate needs of the population. Non-cash here, in fact, are not money, but serve as counting units, with the help of which material resources are distributed. When the barrier between these two spheres is removed, the money supply in circulation is compressed to such an extent that the functioning of the economic system becomes impossible. She begins to fall apart physically. This is exactly what happened during the “reforms”.

Marxist ideology confused everyone

The "strangeness" of the new economic and corresponding financial system baffled the founders of the Soviet state and economists of the 1920s and 1930s. They understood that they were building some kind of economic system unprecedented in history, the like of which had not yet been. They put a lot of effort into understanding it. The problem was that Marxism was adopted as the official ideology in the USSR. But after all, Marx himself, in the economic part of his teaching, proceeded from the realities of Western economics, moreover, of the 19th century. Marx considered such an economy the only possible one that should be created throughout the world. He saw the transformation of the world in the way of changing property relations, but precisely within the framework of a Western-type economy.

Thus, building an economy that had nothing in common with the Western one, the communists came into irresolvable contradiction with Marx himself! This, of course, could not be allowed. Therefore, throughout the entire period of the existence of the USSR, Soviet economists tried to link Soviet practice with Marxism. It turned out bad. Or rather, it didn't work at all. How difficult it was to do this can already be judged by the fact that the first political economy textbook was prepared after thirty years of discussions, only in 1954, after the death of Stalin! Academician K. Ostrovityanov wrote in 1958: "It is difficult to name another economic problem that would cause so many disagreements and different points of view as the problem of commodity production and the operation of the laws of value under socialism." At the same time, I. V. Stalin himself understood that the Soviet economic system was moving further and further away from Marxism. He told his followers: “If you look for answers to all questions from Marx, you will be lost. You have to work with your head."

The well-known researcher Sergei Kara-Murza writes: “Stalin, apparently, intuitively felt the inadequacy of the labor theory of value to what really happened in the economy of the USSR. He resisted the rigid imposition of this theory on reality, but he resisted implicitly and indecisively, without having a final answer for himself. The problem is that the task of building new economy was decided as the sum of momentary answers to current questions. The solution found had no theoretical justification either then or later. The rationale was predominantly ideological. Ideological pressure confused everyone, including economists. As a result, the Soviet economics catastrophically lagged behind the Soviet reality. Now we have to reap the fruits of this lag. Nevertheless, although the theoretical views in the USSR were outdated, the practice still gave quite real results. And that's what we need to keep in mind in the first place.

Lieberman reform

For readers far from economic problems, such a statement may even seem strange. However, in fact, there is nothing unusual in it: in the circles of specialists, these issues have been discussed for many decades. The fact is that the Soviet economic system existed for too short a time and in too difficult historical conditions. As a result, theoretically, it was not really comprehended even in Soviet period. And the "reformers" did not try to understand anything in it, they acted on the principle of "break - do not build." As a result, now we are dealing with an economy, in the principles of which we ourselves do not really understand anything. Our economic science has lagged behind our own reality. This abnormal situation should be corrected long ago.

However, there are serious developments in the field of studying the financial system of the Soviet type. They need to be carefully analyzed. For the first time, the principles of the operation of our financial system began to be widely discussed in the mid-60s, during the discussion economic reform 1965, the so-called "Kosygin reform". The discussion began in 1962 with an article in Pravda by Kharkov professor Yevsey Lieberman. Economists are sharply divided into supporters and opponents of the reform. On the pages of the economic press there was a real war. The discussion has stalled. In the end, Alexei Kosygin, using his power as the pre-council of ministers, simply introduced it by will. With all due respect to Alexei Nikolaevich, we must admit that this decision was erroneous.

What did the “Kosygin reform” offer (in the West it is called the “Lieberman reform”)? Prominent Russian economist V. M. Yakushev characterizes it as follows: “It was assumed that if enterprises could transfer part of their profits to their incentive funds, this would solve the problem of stimulating labor, ensure a reduction in production costs and interest teams in intense plans. But something else happened." But what happened "other"? In short, the reform of 1965 began to undermine the country's financial system, and then the entire economy. The barrier between cash and non-cash (counting units) money, which was previously strictly preserved, began to weaken, i.e. what served exclusively for the purposes of accounting began to turn into a medium of exchange! The negative consequences were not long in coming. Unsecured money supply began to accumulate in the hands of the population and on the accounts of enterprises. Economic units turned out to be interested not in increasing output, but in increasing profits, and disorganization began to grow. economic mechanism etc. As a result, by the beginning of the 1980s, the country approached an economic crisis.

Rising tariffs is not an option

It was the “Kosygin reform” that plunged the USSR into what was later called “stagnation”. “Many scholars were already warning about negative consequences such a decision. But their warnings were ignored” (Yakushev). When “perestroika” began, the “reformers”, instead of restoring the normal for this economic structure the financial system, on the contrary, removed the last barriers between cash and non-cash money supply. This led to disaster. That is why the "reforms" of the 90s were immediately dubbed by serious researchers as "a worsened version of the reform of the 65th year." The strategic mistake in economic policy was made as early as 1965. In the 1990s, the "reformers" only worsened the situation. If the economy has not yet completely collapsed, it is only because some fragments of the former financial system have survived - public sector, individual government programs and other. In addition, some sectors of the economy capable of operating on a self-sustaining basis began to operate, self-employment increased, shuttle trade appeared, and so on. But this situation cannot persist for long. If not change economic policy- the collapse of the system cannot be stopped.

What follows from all this? The economy of the former USSR simply cannot operate on the basis of a Western-style financial system. There, in the general case, the amount of money in the economic turnover must correspond to the mass of goods sold (quantitative theory of money). Simply put, the economy there is financed from the consumer sector. Due to structural features, the Soviet-type economy cannot create the required amount of commodity mass. Therefore, it is necessary to bring the country's financial system in line with the structural characteristics of our economic system. In other words, two financial sectors. One serves the needs of the population, the other - the economic system as a whole. The scope of these sectors should not overlap. Exactly the same conclusions have now been reached by economists throughout the CIS. Thus, the well-known Russian researcher Sergei Kara-Murza writes: “In the USSR there was a financial system of two “circuits”. There was non-cash money in production. On the consumer market- "normal" money. Their mass was regulated in accordance with the mass of goods. This made it possible to support low prices and prevent inflation. Such a system could operate only if the transfer of non-cash money into cash was prohibited. The need to reorganize the financial system is now clear to any serious researcher.

How will this work in practice? A simple example. Now everyone knows that our energy sector is in critical condition and threatens to collapse in the next two years. The authorities are trying to save the day by inflating tariffs endlessly. But the money raised is still not enough. In fact, our population will never be able to finance domestic energy - they have too little money. Therefore, tariffs should not be increased, but reduced. And the financing of the energy industry should be undertaken by the state through special financial channels, strictly isolated and intended only for specific purposes. The funds of the population should be withdrawn exclusively for the remuneration of workers in the industry.

The same applies to heat, water, gas supply, infrastructure and much more. And to shoulder all the costs on the shoulders of the population is meaningless and useless - it still will not pull them. In this case, we will not save the economy, and we will ruin the population. Of course, in reality, everything is much more complicated than it can be stated in a newspaper publication. But we hope that we have managed, at least in general terms, to give readers an idea of ​​the principles on which our financial system should function.

There is little information on the topic of dual-circuit monetary systems. Below is a selection of theses by Andrey Devyatov on the Asian mode of production from this speech of his at the School common sense February 17, 2017:

Economic development is not necessarily guaranteed by a credit economy (Western model). This model is based on the Newtonian understanding of time as a duration or a linear sequence of events (progress). In this model, future demand is monetized, and credit is the main development tool.

The Chinese model of economic development is based on a cyclic understanding of time as a sequence of events, and the key concept is timeliness (which is not in the Newtonian model, where all periods of time are equivalent). This model is built on the law of change, which in the economic part is based not on credit, but on dividing the monetary system into two circuits.

The Asian mode of production is the two-circuit monetary system. It was invented in China in the 12th century during the Song Dynasty, but this system was used in the Yuan Dynasty during the unified state of Genghis Khan. It was thanks to this model that a single state (Yi Guo) from sea to sea could exist. The collapse of the model occurred after the introduction of Western elements into it.

The essence of the model is the division of monetary circulation into natural and non-cash money. The consumption of an individual is provided with natural money (gold, silver), which can be used to buy food or a cow there.

Long-term infrastructure projects (dams, canals, roads) are financed from another circuit, which operates on debt securities issued by the state. In China, paper money was invented specifically for this.

Two circuits - cash and non-cash - are separated, the borders between them are protected by the state through money changers, where you can exchange coins for paper and vice versa.

The fundamental difference from the European way of financing is the understanding of time as a cycle. Therefore, infrastructure projects are not financed by credit, i.е. under the future demand, but under the return of time in a new cycle. Because in the next cycle of life, investments will not pay off with a profit (Western model), but will be used by the next generation of people for a new cycle of life.

In the USSR, a two-circuit system was introduced by Stalin (golden ruble for the population and cashless payments for infrastructure projects). Therefore, after the war, the main priority for Stalin was the nuclear and missile projects as guarantors of the survival of future generations. The main non-cash resources from the second monetary circuit were thrown at them.

Capitalization in the understanding of Stalin - in happiness. The subject of capitalization is the happiness and dream of the people, and not the interest on the loan. It is a dream that can provide colossal economic breakthrough, which was demonstrated by the USSR.

The collapse of the double-circuit monetary system in the USSR occurred as a result of the Kosygin reform, when planning in pieces was abandoned and they switched to monetary statistical equivalents.

With a planning system in kind, innovation is the main indicator. After the Kosygin reform, the introduction of innovations turns out to be unprofitable, because it is possible to ensure the growth of "monetary" statistical indicators in more "efficient" ways: by accelerating costs, increasing costs, etc.


2022
ihaednc.ru - Banks. Investment. Insurance. People's ratings. News. Reviews. Loans